Microsoft powerpoint - ian forester ip competition in a globalised economy
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy Abuse of IP rights in the Light of Article 102 TFEU National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies (GRIPS) Ian S. Forrester, Q.C. EU-Japan Centre for Industrial Cooperation White & Case LLP Tokyo, 22 February 2011 IP and Antitrust: General Principles
Undeniable tension between rewarding innovation with monopoly (IP rights) and encouraging competition
Pursuit of Harmony:
IP rights are not immune from competition law No “inherent conflict” between IPRs and EU competition rules:
Same basic objective of promoting consumer welfare “Both intellectual property rights and competition are necessary to promote
innovation” (Technology Transfer Guidelines, ¶ 7)
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
IP and Antitrust: EU Regulatory Framework
Competition rules: European competition rules highly developed in substance and actively enforced
IP laws still substantially governed by the national laws at Member State level
BUT: EU directives harmonise many aspects of national rules on IP protection, including the enforcement of IP rights and some unitary EU IP rights (trademark, design rights) have been created
EU competition law has constrained national law and exercise of national IP rights in many areas
Each conflict involves anxious debate; usually competition has prevailed
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
IP & Abuse of Dominance: Compulsory Licensing IP & Abuse of Dominance: Compulsory Licensing
When does Article 102 override the exclusive right conferred by
Volvo-Veng (1988): Generally not, but … Magill (1991): Yes, exceptionally, if refusal blocks consumer access to a specific new product
The BBC would not deliver a multi-channel TV guide and used copyright to
IMS (2004): Yes, if four conditions are met:
indispensable, absolute, not just desirable; new product, consumer demand not met; no objective justification; elimination of all competition
Microsoft (2007): Yes, if it would help develop new products?
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
Microsoft Judgment of 2007 (1)
Nature of Sun’s request
Endowing Microsoft’s competitors with the capacity to participate perfectly in a Windows server network as a full member of the family, not as an outsider
Microsoft had to undertake laborious and costly research to document the way its software interacts and licence the results of this research (specifications) to its competitors
When must a dominant company license its IP?
Ensure viable competition, not just weak competition
Simply surviving in the market does not suffice: must ensure viability
Elimination of effective / viable competition in absence of license
Substantial market share of competing products did not exclude Microsoft’s possible duty to
Foresight: applies even if elimination of competition may be some years ahead (damage to
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
Microsoft Judgment of 2007 (2)
Absence of objective justification
Unclear what would suffice as justification, since secrecy and effort are rejected
Licence may promote technical development (not the emergence of a specific new product)
No guidance as to what would qualify as “technical development” Aimed at a rival seeking a license to produce the same product as the dominant player but simply adding an additional feature
Process rather than product approach: no specific new product needs to be identified
Difficult to see the limiting principles
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
IP & Abuse of Dominance: Pharmaceutical Sector Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry - Background
Launched on 15 January 2008
Numerous questionnaires sent to stakeholders (originators, generics, marketing authorisation authorities, parallel traders, wholesalers and national competition authorities): millions of items in response
Preliminary report published on 28 November 2008 and Final Report published on 8 July 2009
Something 'rotten' in EU pharmaceutical sector…
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry – Main Issues
Conduct of pharmaceutical companies
The European Commission believes that competition in the pharmaceutical sector is imperfect
Delays in generic entry, including because of:
Patent litigation, notably when based on secondary patents Patent settlement agreements
Decline in number of new medicines reaching market
“Defensive patenting”
Skepticism about the utility of patents
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry – Implications (1)
Both agreements and abuse of dominance are at stake
Patent settlement agreements will be the biggest issue going forward as Article 101 TFEU applies to all companies
1st Monitoring Exercise (January 2010): companies had to provide the Commission with all settlement agreements concluded between July 2008 and December 2009
2nd Monitoring Exercise (January 2011): Commission asks for all settlements concluded in 2010
Still unclear what the Commission’s position is…
Critique
Settling litigation is normally a positive step; judges are unpredictable A situation where the generic enters market prior to patent expiry may be viewed differently from a situation where the generic exits the market
US concerns about patent settlements do not easily translate to Europe given regulatory differences (no Hatch-Waxman in EU)
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry – Implications (2)
When asked in the early 1970s by Henry Kissinger about the impact of French Revolution, Zhou Enlai, then Premier of China, responded “it is too soon to say.”
The same can be said about the impact of an inquiry on the European pharmaceutical industry: so far there has been a large amount of stress and debate, but not much new policy
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry – Implications (3)
Guidance might emerge in a number of pending cases:
Boehringer (COPD) – formal proceedings opened on 29 March 2007 Servier (perindopril) – formal proceedings opened on 8 July 2009 Investigation into generic practices in France – dawn raids conducted on 6 October 2009
Lundbeck (citalopram) – formal proceedings opened on 7 January
Nexium (esomeprazole) – dawn raids in several Member States on 30 November 2010
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
AstraZeneca – Commission Decision (2005)
Commission’s theory: AstraZeneca abused dominant position by blocking or delaying market access for generic versions and preventing parallel imports of Losec (omeprazole)
Two abuses:
AstraZeneca provided misleading information to national patent offices and courts; and
AstraZeneca misused regulatory procedures by selectively de- registering marketing authorisations (MAs)
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
AstraZeneca – General Court (2010) Commission Decision largely upheld Lack of transparency: AZ had to disclose all relevant facts and any underlying legal interpretation Had AZ been transparent about its particular interpretation of SPC Regulation and/or requested a rectification, its conduct may not have been abusive Intent is not a necessary condition for abuse, nor sufficient to establish an abuse Abuse as objective concept Legal standard: AZ “could not reasonably be unaware” “Good faith” no objective justification unless pro-active transparency Conduct still classified as anti-competitive even when such conduct is remedied prior to having an effect (or effect occurs only after dominance)
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
IP & Abuse of dominance: Standards Standard setting agreements – Rambus controversy
Inventors of the asynchronous DRAM
Discussion in JEDEC among manufacturers of DRAMs whether to incorporate this new technology in industry standard for the DRAM
Was there a duty to disclose status of patent applications?
“Patent ambush”.
Complainants asserted that Rambus had in 1991 to 1994 intentionally concealed that it had patents and patent applications which were relevant to technology used in the JEDEC standard, and subsequently claimed royalties for those patents; Rambus claimed that its technology had been hijacked by JEDEC members
When industry members negotiate standards, each is likely to seek its own advantages rather than “higher” industry benefits
Desire for clarity to disclose as to what is obligatory
Settled in 2009, following Rambus' commitment to offer licences with maximum royalty rates for certain memory types and memory controllers in the future
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
Standard setting agreements Horizontal Guidelines (1) Criteria under which the Commission will not take issue with a standard-setting agreement (“safe harbour”): unrestricted participation for all competitors in the markets affected by the standard setting; transparency of the standard-setting procedures; effective access to the standard on fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory (“FRAND”) terms; and a clear and balanced intellectual property rights (“IPR”) policy. Individual assessment of agreements outside the safe-harbour (“effects-based” features): Freedom to develop alternative standards and products Access to the standard Market shares of the goods and services based on the standard Discrimination against any participating or potential members Sufficiently transparent disclosure of IPRs
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
Standard setting agreements Horizontal Guidelines (2)
Standardisation agreements may only be caught under Article 101(1) TFEU if the parties involved have market power
The Guidelines are an improvement on the position taken by the Commission in early stages of the Rambus case
The Guidelines are still very prescriptive and not practical in every specific instance
Many arrangements not covered by the Guidelines can nonetheless be justified as procompetitive
Intellectual Property and Competition in a Globalised Economy
entities compliant with regulations regarding the practice of law in the countries and jurisdictions in which we have offices.
Step Therapy Criteria Step Therapy Group Drug Names Step Therapy Criteria If the patient has tried a Step 1 drug, then authorization for a Step 2 drug may be given. Step 1 Drug(s): Actos, Actoplus Met, Duetact, Januvia, Janumet, Kombiglyze, Onglyza. Step Therapy Group Drug Names Step Therapy Criteria If the patient has tried two Step 1 drugs, then authorization for